Start of a review of the book

  1. Paul Cockshott
    Paul Cockshott
    Mike Macnairs Book on Strategy.

    Paul Cockshott

    Mike Macnair of the Communist Party of Great Britain has recently
    written a book[macnair] whose avowed aim is to reformulate left
    strategy along Kautskian lines. One might say: surely this is a
    retrograde step politically. But in a sense a movement towards
    Kautskyism would be an advance for the official communist
    movement. Macnair distinguishes between the Kautskian trend in
    Social Democracy and right wing Social Democracy. Besides
    recalling how much of orthodox Leninism is actually Kautskyism at
    second hand, Macnair makes the very accurate observation that:

    The coalitionist policy of the right wing of the Second
    International has been, since 1945, the policy of Second
    International socialists and ‘official communists’ alike. The
    substantive difference between them, before first Euro-communism
    and then the fall of the USSR, was that ‘official communists’
    proposed for each country a socialist-liberal coalition that
    would commit to geopolitical formal neutrality combined with
    friendly relations with the Soviet bloc. With the Soviet sheet
    anchor gone, the majority of the former ‘official communists’ are
    at best disoriented, and at worst form the right wing of
    governing coalitions (as is the case with the ex- communists and
    ex-fellow-travellers within the Labour Party in Britain).

    A key discriminating feature of the Kautskian tendency was its
    opposition to coalitions with bourgeois parties and an insistence
    that it would only enter into government when it had the
    requisite majority to rule un-aided. In this sense then, a move
    to Kautskyism would amount to a considerable radicalisation of
    the communists in Europe. So the book is significant. I will
    argue however, that it is marked by a failure to go beyond
    certain fatal limits of classical social democracy, and also by a
    failure to have any positive theory of socialism. This lack of a
    theory of socialism is first evident in a non-treatment of the
    history of the USSR and China, and later in a failure to spell
    out what sort of economy the socialist movement should be
    fighting for. On the first point he writes:

    Under the Soviet-style bureaucratic regimes there was no
    objective tendency towards independent self-organisation of the
    working class. Rather, there were episodic explosions; but to the
    extent that the bureaucracy did not succeed in putting a
    political cap on these, they tended towards a pro-capitalist
    development. The strategic line of a worker revolution against
    the bureaucracy - whether it was called `political revolution' as
    it was by the orthodox Trotskyists, or `social revolution' by
    state-capitalism and bureaucratic-collectivism theorists - lacked
    a material basis.

    He extends the argument to apply to orthodox Stalinists who have
    to explain why the real Stalinists were not able to organise
    opposition to the restoration of capitalism. This is an
    interesting observation but it has two drawbacks.

    1. Its focus is exclusively on the USSR and Eastern Europe post
    WWII. It ignores the experience of China during the Cultural
    Revolution, and if Getty[getty1985origins] and others are to be
    believed, the experience of the Great Purges. There was working
    class participation there. Did this arise from an 'objective
    tendancy'?

    2. It could be a council of despair. Since the abolition of
    private capitalism is bound to remove the old class struggle
    between labour and capital over profits. If such trades union
    struggle is a precondition of class consciousness, then
    socialism is bound to remove that class consciousness. Whether
    it is bureaucratic socialism or not. What then is to be the
    social basis of resistance to capitalist restoration.

    He argues with respect to the USSR

    What happened instead was to render concrete the 1850s warnings
    of Marx and Engels against the premature seizure of power in
    Germany,16 which formed the basis of Kautsky’s ‘caution’ in the
    1890s and 1900s. By choosing to represent the peasantry and other
    petty proprietors (especially state bureaucrats), the workers’
    party disabled itself from representing the working class, but
    instead became a sort of collective Bonaparte. The Bolshevik
    leaders could see and feel it happening to themselves,17 and in
    1919-1923 the Comintern flailed around with a succession of
    short-lived strategic concepts, each of which would - it was
    hoped - break the isolation of the revolution. These strategic
    concepts are not simply rendered obsolete by the collapse of the
    USSR in 1991. The fate of the other ‘socialist countries’ also
    proves them to be a strategic blind alley.

    This was of course like the argument of Kautsky during the 20s.
    Is it valid to say that the CPs represented petty proprietors
    when in power?

    Well there is some truth in it to the extent that so long as
    petty peasant production existed, it created wings within the CPs
    who defended its interest Bukharin, Gomulka, Deng. But these were
    just one wing, and in most cases they did not come out on top. In
    the USSR private peasant agriculture was largely eliminated by
    collectivisation. And during the 50s and 60s, state farms
    expanded at the expense even of collectives. In Poland after 56
    the pro-petty proprietor wing did come out on top, but that was
    not generally the case. In the DDR, CSSR and Bulgaria state or
    collective agriculture was the rule. The crisis of the socialist
    system, Poland aside, was not generally precipitated by the
    demands of petty proprietors in agriculture. The identification
    of state bureaucrats with petty proprietors is an unconvincing
    throwaway phrase, not justified by any argument.